The negative burden of high fuel
cost
E. Ablorh-Odjidja, Ghanadot
January 11, 2011
The government's fuel price
increases began on January 4, 2011; the reason being that it
has been “forced to increase the prices due to the rise in
the price of crude oil on the international market.”
The change adds 30% more to the
cost that Ghanaians are already paying for petrol and diesel
at the pump, thus continuing the trending practice of the
year-to-year increases in fuel prices.
With the years, Ghanaians have their policy planners to thank
for the unreasonable rises
in fuel cost.
At issue today must be why the
high cost, even with the government’s claim that it provides
subsidy on fuel.
Another must be why the
government, with the tremendous resource at its disposal,
has not been able to develop yet the efficacy for hedging
crude prices to protect Ghanaians from price fluctuations on
the world market.
But before wondering further,
there is another twist, this time told by the National
Petroleum Authority of Ghana (NPA).
According to them the hedging is done, but:
“The hedging is only for 50
percent of our domestic consumption so if prices go up,
there will still be a review upwards because we only hedge
50 percent,” said the Chief Executive of the NPA, Mr. Alex
Mould, to Citi Business news.
I will love for someone to
explain further the rationale behind the need for only the 50% hedging.
Hedging or not, what I know so
far is that even when prices at the world market decrease,
our local pump prices continue to go up when compared to the
immediate, previous years.
This is a condition that begs one
to ask the NPA if Ghana buys her crude from the same source
as other countries.
Presumably and from the price at
the local pumps, Ghana must have bought her crude at a
higher rate than the United States.
In the United States, a gallon of
regular fuel is now selling at an average of $3.00 per
gallon, without subsidy from the government, whereas in
Ghana the same is at about $5.00, with subsidy.
Fuel prices in the United States
are for many parts heavily taxed at State and Federal levels
and still appear comparatively lower at the pump than in
Ghana.
While there are many factors to
pricing fuel at the pump, the factors in Ghana are hard to
identify, explain or understand.
In Canada for instance,
components for fuel cost follow in this general direction:
Crude price is at 47% of the
final product at the pump, 19% for marketing and refining,
and 34% for taxes (info provided by Canadian Petroleum
Institute).
The institute says “Excluding
taxes, the price of gasoline in Canada is practically the
same as in the United States.”
Can the NPA tell us what
percentage of the fuel cost in Ghana is pure tax, or there
is none?
As for hedging, Mr. Mould says:
“Hedging remains relevant because
it is the government that will decide to absorb (the price
increase) or not, and when the government absorbs, the
question is, how does the government get paid for that, does
it have any relief from somewhere?
“The relief comes from hedging.
If you do not hedge you have the whole brunt of the price
increase. If you hedge you have part relief coming from the
benefits of the hedge…”
Nicely told, but hedging is a
risk management tool.
Its only objective can only be derived as leading to
low cost at the pump.
The high cost at the pumps in Ghana, therefore,
is the evidence for the failure of the hedging effort.
The idea of edging is not at
fault, since it is only a tool for risk management.
The question is whether our practitioners have the
maturity, experience, and sophistication to manage the
process well, or have they been bumbling
all along?
The public must know, that as
much as the NPA has remained ambiguous about gains or losses from
their hedging practices, the increases at the fuel pump at
the pump have always been indicative of their lack of
success with the hedging practice.
The failure in hedging has left
our successive governments dependent on the pumps as
collection sources for additional revenue.
In a practical sense, this
approach is far-reaching and can be described as fungible
because everybody pays.
But the problem, as we may later see, places a heavy
penalty on the poor.
High taxes at the pump, like all
things excessive, are counter-productive in several ways.
They burden economic growth; the
more the exercise on fuel the higher the cost impact on the
production of goods and services.
And the cost is amplified as it is passed onward into
public transportation.
The cost spirals downward to
impact the poor at the retail level.
Everything that depends on
transportation will find cost increases, from food at the
table to boarding the bus for work.
The poor, again, may see their net income from
legitimate work drastically reduced.
And the driver of this negative impetus is the
government's confusing taxation on fuel at the pump.
One thing that heavy taxation
cannot prevent is avoidance and the incentive for the
corrupt to cheat at the pump.
And in a nation such as ours, that most of the time
finds corruption excusable, the heavy price at the fuel
pumps will make fraud at these locations more forgivable.
There will be ways for many to
escape the taxation at the pumps.
The well-off may escape the tax bite by limiting
their trips to the pump.
However, the working poor, on whose back much of hard
labor rest, may not be able to escape the cost at all.
It is not the case that there
should be no taxes on fuel, but how far up must the cost of
fuel rise? And
will the government know this peak when it happens, or it
will just happily continue to milk the fuel pumps?
The truth is, the pump prices
will rise because of the need for an easy taxation approach.
But at some point, there will be a disappointment.
The entire economy will be depressed by the overall
burden, and dwindling revenue for the government will occur.
And some social consequences may
also result.
Faced with reduced income because
of the heavy cost of living, the poor may prefer idleness to
work that pays so little.
And it is at this level that society suffers the most
as people become more dysfunctional; the poor are held
back from work and chances for all potential producers
are wrecked.
Yet the cost of the social upkeep
will not be reduced.
The government in the end will be left with a
dilemma; to create incentives to put more people to work or
increase taxes to cover those who do not work.
Increases at the pump will
certainly not help either way.
E. Ablorh-Odjidja, Publisher
www.ghanadot.com, Washington, DC, January 11, 2011
Permission to publish: Please
feel free to publish or reproduce, with credits, unedited.
If posted at a website, email a copy of the web page to
publisher@ghanadot.com. Or don't publish at all.
|